One of the
most interesting areas of financial research these past ten years has come,
oddly, not from economists or investment researchers, but psychologists, who
are pioneering a branch of study known as "behavioral finance." This has led to one of the strangest sights
in the history of Nobel prizes: the 2002 prize in economics handed out to
psychologist Daniel Kahneman for (according to the Nobelprize.org website) "having
integrated insights from psychological research into economic science,
especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under
uncertainty."
The
behavioral finance research tells us that most people take mental shortcuts to
arrive at decisions, and some of them lead to odd conclusions. Around the time you make your New Year's
resolution to lose weight, do you buy a $500 annual membership to a gym or opt
for a $10 per visit pay-as-you-go fee?
Most people who choose the former end up actually going to the gym less
than once a month; the flat fee is only a bargain when you assume that the bold
post-resolution intention will actually happen, but it's often a terrible deal
when a person's actual behavior is taken into account.
How do you
decide whether to be an organ donor when you face the option on your driver's
license application? In countries where
the default option is yes (you consent to be an organ donor), 90% of
individuals happen to be registered organ donors. In countries where the default option is no,
the percentage ranges from 10% to 30%.
This
research is now finding its way into the hands of policy makers, who are
pioneering a new governmental role of protecting you against the dangers of
your own mental shortcuts. One recent
example is automatic enrollment in a company retirement plan. Research shows that if people are required to
affirmatively opt-into having a portion of their paycheck sent to their 401(k)
retirement plan, they will do so at a lower rate (67%) than if they are enrolled
by default and have to affirmatively opt-out (77%). The U.S. government has been encouraging
auto-enrollment policies at American corporations, on the theory that workers
will be better off if more of them are making regular 401(k) plan contributions.
Another
example in Britain came when the government offered tax incentives for people
to insulate their attics, reducing energy consumption and the associated
pollution from energy production. But so
few people showed an interest in the incentives that the UK government finally
had to switch tactics. It offered the
same tax break, but added a loft clearance service that would help people clean
out their attic and give them assistance in disposing of (sell or throw away)
unwanted items. The new service tripled
insulation participation rates.
When the
city of Copenhagen painted green footprints on the sidewalks leading to litter bins, littering decreased by 46%.
The idea of
applying behavioral economics to political and social initiatives sounds a lot
like manipulation to its critics, who worry that we are moving toward a
"nanny state" where the government feels compelled to protect us from
our own behavioral biases. Reducing
litter on the streets of Copenhagen is relatively noncontroversial, but what
about initiatives that try to influence buyers to select more energy-efficient
cars? Or government policies that
discourage the consumption of certain foods or beverages? The New York City ordinance against large
soda containers was based on the assumption that people were unable to recognize,
on their own, the health risks of soda consumption.
Interestingly,
at least one of these behavioral initiatives is now showing evidence of
backfiring. The Center for Retirement
Research at Boston College found that companies that have switched to automatic
enrollment in their 401(k) plans have been paying for the additional cost by
giving their employees smaller employer matches--3.2%, compared with an average
3.5% for plans without automatic enrollment.
At the same time, the Boston College researchers and the Vanguard
organization have found that for some workers, the automatic savings rate
offered in the default is lower than what many workers would have chosen if
they had made an affirmative decision to participate. Worse, the automated mix of investments
(typically target date funds) that is the default option has underperformed the
investment mixes that workers have tended to select on their own. For some workers, at least, the government's
behavioral finance nudge will cost them real money.
No comments:
Post a Comment